Greece’s economy finally on the rise?

After being in a debt crisis since 2009, consumer confidence is at its highest level since 2000 and GDP is expected to have almost 2 percent growth following the fiscal year.

Greece’s GDP Growth up until July 2019. The final quarter will be out at the end of the fiscal year!

How did Greece’s debt crisis get even worse after 2015?

Back in 2015, Greece was still trying to move in a positive direction following an already six year debt crisis. So when the July elections of 2015 came around, the people believed they needed drastic change and elected Alexis Tsipras and his super “left-winged” Syriza party to try and move the economy forward for a change. Tsipras implemented corporate taxes, regulations on international trade, and tons of entitlement programs that the government could not pay for. All of these policies made the debt escalate further which created a major recession.

Alexis Tsipras, the former leader of the Syriza party and prime minister of Greece



The Change in the Right Direction!

Greek citizens became extremely frustrated at the results of Tsipras and the Syriza party through their term, and earlier this year in the July elections opted to elect Kyriakos Mitsotakis, leader of the fiscally conservative “New Democracy” party. After years of different right and left-winged parties running the economy, Greece finally has returned to the two-party system that had them flourish in 2000. Many people worldwide were scared prior to the election that Greece would lean toward right-winged extremism”, but “The New Democracy” party beat out the right-winged “Golden Dawn” party to ensure that democracy is still alive and can flourish again in Greece. Mitsotakis did just that, reversing the socialist agenda that plagued the economy prior to his election. Mitsotakis has implemented corporate tax cuts, lifted restrictions on international trade, and limited entitlement programs within Greece since the government cannot afford it yet. He will continue to reform and work on these policies in the next couple of years as well. These policies are predicted to help the economy grow further and cause GDP to have 2 percent growth at the end of this fiscal year saw. Even though Mitsotakis has just been elected, many economists now believe the Greek economy is stable and will continue to get even better as the economy is at its best since 2000.

The prime minister of Greece, Kyriakos Mitsotakis.


Returning to Normality!

Greece’s capital controls and restrictions are a thing of the past with Mitsotakis in office. Unemployment is still the biggest issue in the Greek economy, but it’s down to 17 percent from its peak at 28 percent in 2013. Granted, many Greek workers do not get fired, as discussed in class last week, so people of college-age or in their young 20’s have a hard job getting employed. That problem is not only an economical issue but a political one as well which makes it hard to judge Greece’s economy on that 17 percent unemployment. Because international trade does not have as many restrictions anymore, Greece is all of a sudden a player in the foreign market, which in the next couple of years will spur the economy to grow even more. Another policy Mitsotakis has implemented is the banks getting rid of “non-performing” or “bad” loans which is set to help grow the economy as well. Greece’s new finance minister Christos Staikouras plans to re-pay 3 billion of Greece’s 8.5 billion euro debt this year as well. All of these policies are not only moving the Greek economy forward but also preventing it from future crashes.

Sources: https://www.ft.com/content/c2c42066-d93c-11e9-8f9b-77216ebe1f17 https://tradingeconomics.com/greece/gdp-growth-annual https://www.southeusummit.com/europe/greece-marks-major-economic-milestone-in-advance-of-a-month-of-financial-planning/

Is It Time To Walk out? How the Strikes Indicate the Business Cycle.

Labor strike has a long history since the industrial revolution, dating back to early 19th century in Europe. It is rarely a top news today. The barista who made a coffee for you at Starbucks, the cleaner who mopped the floor at McDonalds, and your favorite barber at the street corner, may have once protested on the streets.

Fast food workers went on strike at East Los Angeles. Photo taken by Moting Jiang.

It won’t disturb you too much under most circumstances, unless, for example, the angry railway workers make the company cancel your train. But to some extent, the labor strike can tell you what’s happening to our economy, which might somehow impact your life.

Worker strikes can have a wide range of incentives, and in this blog we focus on the economic ones, that is, those over mandatory issues such as wages, working hours, union rights and so on. It is not hard to detect that the number of economic strikes fluctuate yearly. At certain points the workers seem much more proactive than usual, and we can name this phenomenon as the strike cycle. Does it remind you of something? Our economy has periodic expansion and recession too, referred to as the business cycle. Does these two cycles correlate?

Conceivably, it is assumed that strikes occur more frequently and last longer at the period of economic recession; the album of economic depression always contains the pictures of desperate penniless workers marching on the roads. The employers intend to lower the wages and dismiss the employees in an attempt to make their shrinking business survive, consequently arousing disputes and frustrations. However, regarding the demand and the supply of the job market, it is also likely that employees are less inclined to strike when they are at a risk of being crowded-out, while their bargaining power improves during economic expansion. If the workers are rational and self-interested, seemingly they will not irritate their boss when they are losing money.

What Studies on Historical Data Tell Us

A 1952 study by Rees compares the Bureau of Labor Statistics(BLS) series on monthly strikes with the reference business cycle of the National Bureau of Economic Research(NBER) after WWI. It concludes that there is a significant conformity between the two cycles, and the strike peak constantly precedes the business one (Figure 1). Rees explains that the strike represents the tension between union and employers. When the economic expansion is starting, the union has higher expectations while the employers react negatively to it, so their divergence reaches the maximum level.

Figure 1. Credit to Rees, A. (1952). Industrial Conflict and Business Fluctuations. Journal of Political Economy, 60(5), p.361

Some scholars focus on the the relations between strike duration and the business cycle instead. The Institute for the Study of Labor issued a paper in 2008, citing over ten thousand strikes recorded by the Engineering Employers Federation in Great Britain from 1920 to 1970. It discovered that the labor strike duration is countercyclical, that is, the strike will last longer at the time of economic upturn. Additionally, higher employment rate usually enables the union to achieve better outcomes.

It should be noticed that some economists are highly suspicious of the strike data as an economic indicator, concerning that (1) the strike can be driven by political activities such as election and political campaign;  (2)the strikes, like many human activities, can be random and irrational. Scully wrote after studying the strike cycle in mid-20th century that “there is no relationship between the strike cycle and the business cycle” in the long term (while in the short run they do correlate).

Work Stoppage and Economic Cycle in Post-WWII U.S.

What does the labor strike data tell us about the U.S. economics in the past 80 years?

According to BLS statistics, the number of labor strikes in U.S. since 1940s has gradually declined, while still having a cyclical pattern (Figure 2).  BLS only recorded the days of idleness since 1980s, and it also displayed similar pattern(Figure 3).  With reference to the business cycle defined by NBER (Table 1), it is found out that the strike frequency never peaked during the recession. Except for 1948-1950 and 1957-1958 recession, when the economy is shrinking, workers are less inclined to protest on streets than they were in the previous year. When it comes to the strike duration, such correlation is less apparent, partly due to the lack of statistics. But it is still safe to claim that labor strikes usually lasted shorter than last year if the economic downturn is going on.

Table 1. The U.S. reference business cycle since the WWII. Credit to NBER https://www.nber.org/cycles/recessions.html
Figure 2. Data retrieved from Bureau of Labour Statistics and graph generated by the author. See BLS database at https://www.bls.gov/wsp/

Figure 3. Data retrieved from Bureau of Labor Statistics and graph generated by the author. See BLS database at https://www.bls.gov/wsp/

The above-mentioned evidences support the argument that labor strikes increase as the economy booms in order to maximize the union’s bargaining power. Nevertheless, business cycle can not account for all the characteristics of the strike cycle. For instance, the fluctuation of labor strike became very minor after 1990s, and it did not rise up significantly from 1991 to 2001 when the economic blossomed for almost a decade. Potential explanations lie in the development of union trades and labor rights legislation.

In conclusion, Labor strike data reflects the union’s behaviors as rational players in the economy. Trade unions are more likely to organize working stoppage when the business cycle is at its top, and workers are less likely to protest when the economy is falling down and offering less jobs. However, given that other factors especially the political events also exert an essential impact on trade union’s decision-making, it requires more caution to treat strike data as an economic indicator.

Reference

Scully, G. (1971). Business Cycles and Industrial Strike Activity. The Journal of Business, 44(4), 359-374. Retrieved from http://www.jstor.org/stable/2352052

Rees, A. (1952). Industrial Conflict and Business Fluctuations. Journal of Political Economy, 60(5), 371-382. Retrieved from http://www.jstor.org/stable/1826482

Devereux, P. J., & Hart, R. A. (2011). A good time to stay out? Strikes and the business cycle. British Journal of Industrial Relations, 49, s70-s92.

U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. https://www.bls.gov/

The National Bureau of Economic Research.https://www.nber.org/cycles/recessions.html