Behind ‘fast fashion’ brands are underpaid workers working in sweatshops

Lured by the promise of a restaurant job paying $1,000 a month, Yeni Dewi travelled to the United States on a tourist visa in 2013. Once here, she realized she had been trafficked. She was forced to work as a domestic help at a house in Sherman Oaks near Santa Monica. She worked 18 hours daily and was paid $200 every 35-38 days. She managed to escape after a couple of years and has been a garment worker ever since.

Currently she works at a garment manufacturing factory near the intersection of Wall Street and 8th Street on the outskirts of the Fashion District in downtown L.A. Dewi said that the factory is a supplier for Fashion Nova. But she earns around $300-$350 per month even though she works for at least 40 hours every week.

“I don’t like the situation…but I have no other choice,” said Dewi, who is mother to a daughter here and a son who lives back home Indonesia with his grandmother.

Yeni Dewi with her daughter

According to a report by CIT Group Inc. and the California Fashion Association, the fashion industry in Los Angeles generates at least $18 billion in revenue. However, behind the world of mass-produced garments from fast fashion brands like Zara, Forever 21 and Fashion Nova, lies an underbelly of exploited workers receiving less than minimum wage and working in sweatshop conditions.

The minimum wage in the City of Los Angeles is presently $12 or $13.25 an hour, depending on the size of the business. According to the first quarterly report of 2018 of the California Employment Development Department, the hourly median wage of a worker in the garment and textile industry was $11.81. Despite state law mandating that all garment workers must be paid at least the minimum wage, many say that they don’t even get half of the designated amount.

“We are earning like $5 an hour right now, when every year it [the minimum wage] rises up to $12, $13 and so on,” she said. “In L.A, the minimum wage rises every year, but the piece rate never rises.”

According to the piece rate, each garment worker is paid around 70 cents for each “operation” like stitching the sleeves to the main body of a dress or joining the two sides of a shirt. Dewi said the total amount earned by a worker per garment depends on the style, but generally comes to around $2.

Mariella Martinez of the Garment Worker Center said that part of the reason that garment workers receive such low wages is that the big, sometimes multinational, brands that the factories supply refuse to increase their prices. This puts the onus solely on the owners of the factories to pay decent wages. The owners, in turn, are often unwilling to cut into their own profits. They also have to compete with manufacturing plants in Asia or Central or South America where labor is cheaper and labor laws are less stringent.

“If it is $15 an hour [for labor] in the United States and in California, that is a day’s labor in Mexico and two days’ labor in China,” said Ilse Metchek, the president of the California Fashion Association.

The Association, which Metchek said deals with, “the voice of the industry, the business of the business,” was formed in 1995 in the aftermath of the El Monte Slavery Case.

Metchek said that manufacturing has decreased in Los Angeles and will keep on decreasing over the years. The industry however is still huge. In 2016, Business Wire found that wholesalers in the industry added roughly 1500 jobs each year.

In 2016, researchers from UCLA studied the wage claims processed through the Garment Workers Center and found that workers earn an average of $5.15 an hour. Despite state legislation that holds manufacturers liable for wage and hour violations in the garment manufacturing industry, there is also little governmental oversight or enforcement.

Many of the factories operate illegally in garages, sheds, or abandoned properties, making it very difficult for government agencies to monitor them, said Dewi. They also do not provide health benefits, holidays or insurance and workers often have to work in sweatshop conditions.

Dewi has worked in factories where there were no bathroom or lunch breaks and the workers there had to bring their own clean water and toilet paper, she said.

Virgilda Romero, another garment worker, also described working in unsafe and unhygienic conditions.

“I worked at a factory between Broadway and Main streets on Adams where things were really bad…They would make me do a lot of the cleaning. So I would be in charge of cleaning the bathrooms and also like catching killing the rodents and then so I would deal with like rat pee falling on me and things like that,” said Romero. “I wouldn’t work sometimes on Sundays and they would leave the trash over, so there would be like maggots in the trash.”

Virgilda Romero at the Garment Worker Center

Romero arrived in the United States from Guatemala in 2001. She has worked in the garment manufacturing industry for more than 16 years. The first factory she worked at paid only 5 cents a piece. She has also worked in places where the employers would pressure her to work faster and not allow her to take any breaks. There have been times when she worked for 11 hours a day, Monday through Saturday, and sometimes even on Sundays to earn enough to survive.

Romero said that her present employer was much better and pays her around $470 for six-day weeks. Even then, when she informed her that she would be unable to work for some days due to a surgery, she got very upset and said, “You’re going to miss work again. You better get healthy quick so that you can come back to work as soon as possible.”

“I was very nervous because I’ve been taking these medications that make me have to go to the bathroom a lot because of the surgery and I was, you know, kind of scared the whole time that she would get angry for taking so many restroom breaks,” said Romero.

According to the California Bureau of Labor Statistics, 71 percent of the garment workers are immigrants, mostly Latinx and Asians. While both Romero now has valid work permit, many of the workers are undocumented immigrants and some are, like Dewi, victims of human trafficking.

The owners of the factories easily take advantage of their workers because they know that they are in precarious positions and will be too scared to go to the authorities to file wage claims or complaints about work conditions, Martinez said. Many are simply not aware that even though they are undocumented, they still enjoy certain rights.

For instance, Dewi did not speak English or Spanish when she first arrived in the United States. She was also not aware that she had certain rights as a victim of human trafficking. She was hiding both from her traffickers and also immigration authorities. She was scared that if she went to the police, they would arrest her for not possessing valid work permits. She did not realize that the garment industry was short-changing her as well.

“When I was working for my traffickers, they only paid me $200 [every 35 days]…and I didn’t get any holidays. In the garment industry, I got like $200 or $150 a week, and I thought it was good,” said Dewi. It was only after lawyers with the Garment Workers Center made her aware of her rights did she realize how low her wages were.

Dewi’s documentation is being processed and she hopes she will soon be able to apply for a green card and bring her son to Los Angeles.

As a member of the Garment Workers’ Center, Dewi often helps them with their campaigns. She said that most importantly the industry needs to abolish the piece rate.

“The first thing we are gonna to do is get minimum wage for the workers and then everything else, step-by-step, said Dewi. “We are gonna ask for health and safety and everything else.”

Bad for Business? The Effects of Legalization on Marijuana’s Black Market

By Roy Pankey

Marijuana is everywhere. That has been true for a long time, but it has become vastly more visible in the last several years. For decades, marijuana users depended on the black market alone to get their hands on the drug. Things changed in 2012 when Colorado voters passed a ballot initiative to legalize cannabis. California is among the nine states (and the District of Columbia) that have followed the Centennial State’s move. More than 65 million Americans now live in states permitting adults to legally consume marijuana for any reason. Legalization advocates argue that regulating cannabis brings the industry into the light where governments can tax pot and effectively eradicate the black market.

A timeline of states’ marijuana legalization. (Third Way)

 

Governor Jerry Brown’s administration estimated $175 million in cannabis tax revenue for the first half of 2018, but the Legislative Analyst’s Office reported revenue of just $34 million in the first quarter, a figure about 80 percent below projections. Why was Brown’s estimate so far off? It isn’t because Californians don’t like weed; legalization doesn’t hinder the black market. In some ways, it aids illicit trade. Though the plant is legal in several states, the marijuana black market has not taken a hit. The legalization of cannabis acts as a shield against suspicions of impropriety, disguising illegal growers as legitimate, enticing sellers to avoid regulation, and dissuading buyers from making regulated purchases. Let’s look at how this works.

The majority of cannabis touches many hands before consumption. The grower plays the inaugural role in the distribution channel. As soon as marijuana is legalized in a jurisdiction, many farms appear after receiving a grower’s license. The sight of marijuana growing operations becomes commonplace, and no one questions the legitimacy of the cultivation. It is at this point, when everyone assumes all growers in the region are licensed, that unlicensed growers establish farms. They hide their illegal setup behind the public’s complacency and are not questioned about their work. NPR reported on an example of this kind of illegal pot farm in Okanogan County, Washington and how it was busted by local authorities. The growers of this farm went as far as trying to dupe their tax assessor. Owners filed to pay agricultural property taxes at the exact rate for licensed cannabis farmers. While unlicensed growers inherently supply the black market, even legal growers find opportunities to contribute to the trade.

 

              Authorities in California fight illegal cannabis. (BBC)

 

Regulation in this business depends on licensed farmers to be forthcoming with their production numbers. Without a way to ensure honesty, some legitimate pot producers take advantage of the system. Growers are required to tag their plants and disclose the number of buds harvested from each plant. Authorities have recognized that farmers often “set aside” buds without counting them. Fraudulent bud counts routinely go unnoticed, as the amount of product a given marijuana plant yields is contingent on several factors, including the amounts of water and sunlight the plant received, whether or not it was treated with fertilizer, the climate in which the plant grows, and more. This unaccounted cannabis automatically becomes part of the black market.

Sellers are the next hands in the supply chain and the next to subject themselves to the same kind of criminal activity in attempt to evade the obtrusive restrictions on marijuana vending and marketing. Before a seller can put their products up for sale, they need a license. Obtaining a license can be an arduous process. In the weeks leading up to California’s legalization of pot, Los Angeles only employed four full-time regulators to sift through licensed seller applications. The lack of staff caused a backlog in application reviews and left countless growers, businesses, and hopeful entrepreneurs in a state of uncertainty, according to Pot Network. Many of the candidates were bogged down by expensive leases and other costs without generating any income, making the prospect of selling marijuana illegally attractive. But people in other cities in California might have considered these fretting applicants lucky.

Sellers in some cities were especially prone to get involved in the black market, because individual California cities were allowed to prohibit any and all legal pot businesses if they want. Many had chosen to do just that. The LA Times reports that about half of Californians reside in cities that banned dispensaries and pot delivery services. There is no doubt that a ban of this magnitude played a role in the state’s sending of more than 2,500 cease-and-desist letters to unlawful marijuana shops as of August. In July, the state’s Bureau of Cannabis Control clarified the law, saying pot delivery companies could deliver to any private address in the state. Deliveries can now be made in any city, whether a city holds to its dispensary ban or not. The bureau hopes to made marijuana accessible to all adults in California regardless of where they live. Employees of delivery businesses still must verify the buyer’s identity and age, another potential deterrent for selling legally.

Weed’s wide fanbase tempts sellers to ignore current legal limitations on who they can take money from. All states that have legalized recreational marijuana mandate buyers be at least 21 years old. The Washington Post reported that 52 percent of users are millennials. While most millennials are now 21 and over, the study found that marijuana use is skewed significantly toward a younger demographic. The report also showed that nearly 55 million Americans currently consume cannabis, while 35 million consume it monthly.

Marijuana usage among Americans. (Washington Post)

 

Marijuana usage among millennials and older users. (Washington Post)

 

This means that a very large number of young people in this country are using the drug. As young Americans—potentially too young to be legal consumers—represent such a large chunk of the pot market, some sellers disregard the law and sell to those under age.

A buyer’s age isn’t the only thing some sellers overlook. In states that allow cannabis for medicinal purposes, some sellers aren’t concerned by whether or not their clients possess the proper licenses for consumption. Currently, it’s legal to smoke marijuana for medical use in 20 states. Medical marijuana refers to the use of cannabis as a doctor-recommended form of medicine or herbal healing. Most states that permit medical pot require patients to hold a medical marijuana card, a license that allows you to smoke pot.

California allowed medical cannabis before it legalized the drug for recreational use. The state’s Medical Marijuana Identification Card Program (MMICP) created a legal license for consuming marijuana and a database used to verify qualified patients and their primary physicians. Last year, getting your license from MMICP was rather easy; any doctor licensed in California could write a recommendation for medical cannabis, and the patient simply had to take the paper to a dispensary. You could even complete the process with an app without ever leaving your house. (Since January 2018, both MMICP and the app have become obsolete.) In states that still require a medical marijuana card, sellers avoid the hassle of asking to see a buyer’s card and verifying their enrollment in the state’s medical use database. All sales finalized without appropriate certification become sales in the marijuana black market. Similar to sellers, buyers participate in the black market to achieve less stressful transactions.

Many buyers turn to illegal pot for the same reasons sellers do, such as for being under age and not holding a valid consumption license (where applicable). Other reasons include lower prices, convenience of the sale, and the guarantee of anonymity. Prices are arguably the biggest reason some people choose to buy weed from the black market. “Sin taxes” on goods such as alcohol, tobacco, and cannabis are notoriously high.  These high rates steer buyers toward cheaper options. Washington state levies a whopping 37 percent sales tax on pot purchases, while Alaska’s government nets $50 for every ounce sold. Reuters reports that while daily users in Canada make up less than 15 percent of marijuana users, they account for nearly 60 percent of the country’s total cannabis consumption.

Distribution of cannabis user and total cannabis consumption in Canada.                                                                           (Reuters)

 

Convenience is another factor that plays into the business of the black market. Not all communities have dispensaries, and some people have to drive lengthy distances to purchase marijuana from the nearest retail store. Buying from unlicensed sellers in these communities is often much easier than the alternative. The avoidance of purchase limits also falls under the convenience umbrella. In some instances, dispensaries must limit your purchase to a particular amount of legal marijuana. With black market dealers, such restrictions don’t exist. Before finalizing a legal sale, the buyer must present a photo I.D. for age verification purposes. This requirement may disqualify those who don’t have a valid form of I.D. due to legal resident status or other reasons. The black market is also attractive to those who wish their favorite habit remain a secret. Sales of illegal pot are executed with far fewer eyes on the sale than regulated sales. If you’re buying illegal pot, you don’t have to worry about being seen in a dispensary by anyone you know or the knowledge of your sale being used in official sales numbers. Black market purchases can be made in cash without leaving a paper or legal trail.

Though recreational cannabis is legal is more states than ever before, the black market for the drug is showing no signs of stopping anytime soon. Illegal growers blend in with legal growers. Legal growers smuggle to states where it’s illegal to sell. Sellers don’t want to spend time trying to verify a buyer’s age and eligibility to consume. Buyers don’t want to pay high taxes on their weed. Roll and repeat.

 

 

 

Sources:

BBC, https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=59w-HQq2x0o

Bureau of Cannabis Control, https://cannabis.ca.gov/wp-content/uploads/sites/13/2018/07/Bureau-of-Cannabis-Control-Proposed-Text-of-Regulations.pdf

CBS Los Angeles, https://losangeles.cbslocal.com/2014/04/30/costa-mesa-man-gets-3-years-for-furnishing-pot-laced-brownies-to-minors/

EazeMD, https://www.eaze.md/

LA Times, http://www.latimes.com/opinion/editorials/la-ed-marijuana-delivery-20180814-story.html

Legislative Analyst’s Office, https://lao.ca.gov/LAOEconTax/Article/Detail/282

NPR, https://www.npr.org/2018/05/16/610579599/despite-legalization-marijuana-black-market-hides-in-plain-sight

Pot Network, https://www.potnetwork.com/news/why-marijuana-legalization-belongs-californias-black-market

Reuters, https://www.reuters.com/article/us-canada-cannabis-blackmarket-insight/why-canadas-pot-legalization-wont-stop-black-market-sales-idUSKCN1J40FS

Tax Foundation, https://taxfoundation.org/state-marijuana-taxes-2018/

Third Way, https://www.thirdway.org/infographic/timeline-of-state-marijuana-legalization-laws

Washington Post, https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/wonk/wp/2017/04/19/11-charts-that-show-marijuana-has-truly-gone-mainstream/?utm_term=.388a41fe4ac5

California’s market-based response to climate change tries to avoid the problems with markets

A layer of smog rests over the Los Angeles Basin in Sept. 2007. (Flickr user vlasta2, CC BY-NC-ND 2.0)

When California Gov. Jerry Brown signed major climate legislation in June, he returned to the spot where his predecessor, Arnold Schwarzenegger, signed his own climate law more than ten years earlier: Treasure Island.

It was an apt location. The artificial island in the San Francisco Bay was created in the 1930s to showcase California’s grandeur for the World’s Fair. Likewise, these climate bills are intended largely to demonstrate to the world that California is leading on climate change.

Schwarzenegger signed Assembly Bill 32 into law in 2006, setting the stage for the creation of California’s cap-and-trade program. A concept that’s been around for only a few decades, cap-and-trade aims to create financial incentives for polluters to adopt more eco-friendly technologies and reduce their greenhouse gas emissions. Brown extended the program to 2030 on Treasure Island and created more ambitious targets.

The state’s goal is to reach 1990 levels of greenhouse gas emissions by 2020, despite a projected population increase of nearly 37 percent over 1990. In 2017, that goal was toughened to reach 40 percent below 1990 levels by 2030.

But so far, it’s been hard to measure the cap-and-trade program’s success, and market-based approaches to the environment can have many of the same flaws and failures found in other kinds of markets. The state’s efforts to address these flaws led to redundant “complementary” policies, meaning that the centerpiece of California’s climate policy actually only plays a small part in its emissions reductions.

A modern cap-and-trade system is designed to reduce greenhouse gas emissions through a flexible market rather than one-size-fits-all regulation. By putting a price on greenhouse gases and creating a market to trade them, the system creates economic incentives for firms to reduce their emissions in the way that’s most cost-effective. To reach the state’s 2020 goal, emissions will need to be about 15 percent below a “business as usual” scenario.

The California Air Resources Board keeps track of the state’s greenhouse gas emissions. This chart from CARB’s 2017 Scoping Plan shows emissions from 2000 to 2014.

To illustrate how this works in practice, let’s imagine you run a natural gas power plant and you produce 100 tons of CO2-equivalent in a year (in reality, this figure would be much higher). Knowing that you emit 100 tons, the California Air Resources Board would issue you 100 carbon credits. You’d get most of them for free, but a few would need to be purchased on the market, either from the state or from other polluters. The idea is that you would save money by taking steps to reduce your emissions rather than purchasing credits, and then if you use fewer than what you’re given for free, you can sell the rest and make a profit. The total number of credits given by the state decreases every year to encourage emissions reductions.

California’s cap-and-trade system began on Jan. 1, 2013, with large power plants and industrial facilities. It was expanded to fuel distributors in 2015, meaning that cap-and-trade now affects about 85 percent of greenhouse gas emissions in the state. Some major companies in the state, like electric utility Pacific Gas and Electric, which serves nearly two-thirds of California’s geographic area, have said they support the program as the best way to address climate change.

In the United States, California has the most extensive cap-and-trade system, which affects all companies emitting more than 25,000 tons of CO2-equivalent in a year. By 2018, its market will be linked to both the Quebec and Ontario emissions markets (more on this later). There’s also a regional cap-and-trade system for electric utilities in New England, and there have been others in the past, such as one created in the 1990s to reduce acid rain-causing emissions. But no nationwide emissions trading system exists today in the U.S. The last big effort to create one, the Waxman–Markey bill in 2009, passed in the House but fell through in the Senate after facing opposition from senators from coal-reliant states.

So far, emissions auctions in California have raised nearly $5 billion for the state, according to the state Legislative Analyst’s Office. State law requires this money to be spent on projects that further reduce greenhouse gas emissions. More than $1.3 billion has been spent on the state’s high-speed rail project, and nearly $700 million each has been spent on low carbon vehicle incentives and affordable housing programs.

Critics of cap-and-trade policy say it’s burdensome for businesses and have pointed to high-profile companies like Toyota moving their operations out of California. But USC environmental economist Kate Svyatets said the state has been successful in balancing competing interests: economic freedom and environmental protection.

“A lot of businesses, instead of being overburdened, they make money,” Svyatets said. “It’s possible to have both a cleaner environment and economic growth, and California shows how to achieve it.”

For most economists, cap-and-trade is the “preferred solution” for regulating greenhouse gas emissions, UCLA researcher Ann E. Carlson wrote in the Harvard Journal on Legislation. Other methods of emissions control, like a carbon tax or mitigation rules, require direct government enforcement and are not as economically efficient as a market system can be — they impose a price on carbon on the state rather than letting one emerge through economic activity.

“It’s hard for the government to decide exactly how many carbon credits to allow,” Svyatets said. “The carbon experts say it’s not expensive enough yet. It’s still better than nothing, but it’s not expensive enough for some companies to switch to clean technology.”

But though California’s cap-and-trade system is designed to create price incentives to reduce emissions, it has not been very instrumental in doing so. The emissions cap each year has been higher than actual emissions in the state, meaning that the emissions trading system does not have the chance to seriously affect how polluters behave. Prices on the emissions market also fell precipitously in 2016 as a court case made the program’s future uncertain. They’ve since rebounded but remain near the state-mandated price floor.

When emission credits don’t cost enough, it becomes cheaper for firms to pollute than to invest in methods that would reduce their emissions in the long term. The European Union is an example of this. It started its cap-and-trade system in 2005, but the European Commission allowed too many credits in the market. Prices fell to ineffective levels by 2008, and companies were profiting off the EU’s mistake by selling the extra credits.

As in California, the prices have since stabilized. At the time of writing, the allowance to emit a ton of greenhouse gases costs roughly $7 in the EU, compared to $13 on California’s market. The 2017 price floor in California is $13.57.

This chart from the European Commission of the European Union shows how the EU’s greenhouse gas emissions have changed since 1990. The data are shown as an index, with 100 being the 1990 level.

Carlson said that when emissions trading systems don’t work, “policymakers may need to enact complementary policies to address those market failures.” California has supplemental requirements like the Renewable Portfolio Standard, which requires an increasing portion of electricity sold in the state to come from renewable and emissions-free sources, and the Low Carbon Fuel Standard, which requires gasoline and diesel fuels to be less “carbon-intensive.”

These policies are perhaps the greatest limit to cap-and-trade’s effectiveness. The complementary policies are responsible for about 80 percent of emissions reductions, with cap-and-trade in place to “sweep up remaining cuts,” according to MIT researchers’ interviews with California officials.

All three policies were created together in what the researchers have called an “insurance” policy to “create a mechanism that could make up emission reduction efforts that were lost if any of the major complementary policies were to fail.” In a way, this means that cap-and-trade in California is intended to be largely a backup plan in case the state’s other policies are not enough. This limits the role that the market has and therefore the incentive for polluters to reduce emissions in the most cost-effective way.

One common issue in many markets is a lack of competition or the monopolization of resources, but despite some speculative activities in emissions trading, anti-competitive behavior hasn’t been a problem in large markets like the European Union or California. German researchers found that those kinds of issues only arise in small trading pools, such as the RECLAIM market for nitrous oxide and sulfur oxide emissions in Southern California.

“Firms within the same industry do not want to sell allowances to buyers with whom they [otherwise] compete,” the researchers wrote. But in large cap-and-trade systems with diverse stakeholders, this has not been a problem.

To make emissions trading systems even more competitive, governments have sought to link their markets with others, allowing credits to be sold across them. More buyers and sellers of emissions means more competition and less room for market abuse.

“If you have a very small market, what if nobody wants to buy your allowances? Just imagine you want to sell a used car or your cell phone or something,” Svyatets said. “If it’s just you and I in this market and nobody else, what if I don’t want your cell phone? What if I don’t want your car?”

But linkages introduce a problem seen in other cases of cross-jurisdictional common markets, like the European Union. When the Greek debt crisis struck that country in 2008, leaders at the European Central Bank found their hands tied when it came to monetary policy to relieve the nation’s ensuing recession. According to UCLA researcher Juliet Howland, linked emissions trading systems could face a similar problem in which one government “may not be able to regulate the price of carbon credits in order to prevent serious damage to [its] economy.” The MIT researchers found through their interviews that California’s system was intended to be flexible for linkages with other western states (which later abandoned their cap-and-trade ambitions), but were concerned that it could be hurt by linkages to weaker cap-and-trade markets.

Linked emissions systems don’t even have to be geographically close — California’s market is linked to the province of Quebec and soon to Ontario, while the European Union has started the process of linking its system to Australia’s. The thought is that in tackling a global problem, it doesn’t matter where greenhouse gas emission reductions happen as long as they happen somewhere.

But California has taken steps to ensure local benefits for its cap-and-trade program. Twenty-five percent of funds are automatically earmarked for high-speed rail, plus 20 percent go to affordable housing and 10 percent to transit systems. All revenues from the sales of emission credits on auction go toward programs that the state says promote public health, and by law, one-quarter of revenues must benefit “the state’s most disadvantaged and burdened communities.”

Those communities, it turns out, are some of the most affected by climate change.

California’s cap-and-trade system aims to reverse course on greenhouse gas emissions to help protect all communities from the harmful effects of global climate change. But despite its large potential impact, the program in practice is only secondary to the state’s more heavy-handed regulations.

This chart from the California Air Resources Board’s 2017 Scoping Plan shows that potential statewide greenhouse gas emissions reductions under the continuation of planned policies would exceed those required under the governor’s executive orders.

That could change. The California Legislative Analyst’s Office found in 2017 that the state was on track to meet its 2020 emissions goal, but the 2030 target is much more ambitious and will require much more severe greenhouse gas reductions.

The cap-and-trade program will likely become more essential over time as the cap becomes increasingly tighter, but this will increase the burden on polluters too and potentially increase costs for consumers. The analysts estimated that some policies needed to reach the 2030 target could cost $300 per ton of carbon dioxide equivalent — or more than 20 times the current price for one allowance on the cap-and-trade market.

Who will be hit hardest by the cost of these reductions remains to be seen, and the impact on the economy is unclear. The analysts said long-term carbon prices depend on factors that are “highly uncertain,” and the state Department of Finance does not provide economic growth projections past 2020.

For now, the California Air Resources Board is working on a plan to reach its 2030 emissions goals. What comes out of those meetings will determine the future of California’s climate policy.

Why are states required to have balanced budgets?

With over $20 trillion in amassed debt, the United States federal government is no stranger to running budget deficits. It’s essentially common and expected practice now. For college students my age, the knowledge that there used to be a balanced budget in the US comes as a surprise that almost doesn’t seem real.

But for most state and local governments across the country, balanced budgets aren’t just the norm, but the rule. According to the National Conference of State Legislatures, 43 states require their governor to propose a balanced budget, 39 require the legislature to pass one, and 37 require the budget to continue to be balanced at the end of the fiscal year. In California, the constitution requires the governor to propose a balanced budget and prohibits the passage of a budget in which General Fund expenditures from exceeding General Fund revenues. In cases like California’s, it’s hard for states to even attempt to carry a deficit because their constitutions prevent them from selling bonds to pay for it.

California’s constitution was ratified in 1879. That’s 138 years (ideally) of balanced budgets. So why can’t the federal government do the same?

Spending only as much money as you get is definitely sound fiscal policy to ensure the solvency of the state government, but it does limit what legislatures can do in times of crisis. States and local governments are reliant on taxes on sales, income, and property — revenues that fall in economic recession when people lose their jobs, lose their property, and/or don’t buy as much. At the same time, reliance on safety net welfare programs increases, putting the state in a budget crunch.

Just as in the federal government, a great deal of state spending essentially runs on autopilot and is difficult to control. States take in — and then spend — a lot of money from federal grants or reimbursements, and the way that money is spent is typically determined by the federal government. Other revenues are specifically earmarked by law, such as money from lottery sales or gas taxes. And in other cases, like Proposition 98 in California, the state is required to spend a certain amount of money on specific departments. (Proposition 98 requires California to spend increasing amounts on education based on economic and enrollment growth).

A lack of flexibility can lead to desperate actions when the economy falters. Governments freeze hiring, stop maintaining buildings, cut back services, furlough employees, or renegotiate pension agreements. In 2009, Arizona was so desperate to balance its budget that it sold public buildings as a way to get money fast — including the Capitol, the state fairgrounds, and some prisons. These cuts can have further impacts on what we typically perceive as economic recovery, since state and local government spending makes up about 12 percent of GDP.

Whether this is good or bad depends in many ways on ideology. If state and local governments were allowed to follow the Keynesian model and spend their way out of an economic downturn, that would allow for even more powerful economic recovery efforts. But followers of Friedrich Hayek’s thinking would say that cutting state budgets in times of crisis keeps us rooted in the reality of the services our government gives us — and what they’re worth.

California’s housing crisis: What gives?

It’s no new news that California is experiencing a housing crisis. Just how bad the crisis is might surprise you.

The San Jose Mercury News published an in-depth investigation into the current crisis and finally answered the question: “What gives?” and most importantly “What’s next?”

Home ownership in California is at an all-time low since World War II. The average home price is 2.5 times higher than the average price nationally. With a median cost of around $437,000 more and more people are choosing to rent instead of buy.

While renting may seem like the better option it still takes a toll on residents as nearly 70 percent of poor Californians see most of their paychecks go to constantly rising rent. Couple the cost of rent with student loan debt and you have a crisis.

It can be said that while rent is infinitely more expensive in California than other places, residents are still getting paid more. This is indeed true, however, hidden within the truth is the fact that income has not kept pace with rising home costs.

This large income inequality has led many to move out of California, namely those living on the poverty line. From 2000-2015 800,000 residents have moved out of California to other states including Texas. The average income for the thousands that left in 2007 was $50,000.

Those who choose to tough it out and stay in California often become homeless. Between 2015 and 2016, California saw an uptick in homelessness of about 2,400 people. Housing data website, Zillow estimates that a 5% rent increase in Los Angeles would result in an additional 2,000 homeless people. So far rent has increased 4%.

The study found that such a crisis has large repercussions on the economy as a whole. The McKinsey Global Institute found such crisis cost the economy between $143 billion and $233 billion annually.

So how can California fix its problem before the bubble bursts? The state will once again tackle its long-awaited housing package again this month. While help may be on the way it won’t fix the problem entirely. According to the Legislative Analysts Office, helping the 1.7 million poorest residents would cost around $15 billion at the very least. The Los Angeles times estimates that of the three bills being considered only 25% of that estimation would be provided.